Tuesday, May 24, 2011

 

Fiscal Attraction & Entrepreneurship

Fiscal Fatal attraction and idiosynchracies of entrepreneurs
http://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article.cfm?articleid=2762


How Money Impacts Marriage


When it comes to marriage, do opposites attract? Or do birds of a 


feather flock together? While men and women are known to 


gravitate toward mates with personal qualities similar to their own 


in most respects, Wharton marketing professor Deborah Small 


found the opposite to be true when it comes to money.


find that stingy spenders tend to marry those who splurge freely, 


and vice versa. The pattern amounts to "fatal attraction," the 


researchers argue, because it causes conflicts over money and 


thus has a negative effect on marital well-being.


"There's a lot of academic literature and interest in individual 


decision making, [but what has been] largely neglected is that 


people are often making decisions jointly and the outcomes of 


financial decisions affect other people," Small says. "It's important 


to understand that even though two individuals are involved in a 


decision and are being affected by it, their attitudes and 


preferences may not be aligned."


he majority of relationship research suggests that people are 


attracted to those with similar demographic characteristics, 


attitudes, values and even names. But Small and her co-authors 


based their hypothesis of spendthrift/tightwad attraction on a 


theory that men and women also tend to seek out a mate who 


has qualities that are the stark opposite of those they most strongly 


deplore in themselves -- in this case, the tendency to spend too 


much or too little.


Two subsequent experiments asked different sets of respondents to 


rate their own and their spouses' behavior on the spendthrift-


tightwad scale. In both cases, the researchers found that stingy 


spenders were more likely to be married to profligates and high-


rollers gravitated toward the miserly.


People might think "that someone on the other end of the 


spectrum might heal them in some way," Rick notes. "If I'm a 


tightwad, I want to find a spendthrift to loosen me up, because 


tightwads by definition want to loosen up. Spendthrifts also by 


definition want to change their behavior.... They might think that 


an opposite would help reel in that misbehavior. That [is not] what 


we find."


Even though these couples may have assumed that marrying an 


opposite when it came to money would balance out their own 


behavior and lead to greater financial health, Small and her co-


authors discovered that such matches did not necessarily make for 


happier relationships. Indeed, the research shows that conflicts 


over money created more marital strife for these "opposites 


attract" couplings. "We have some findings suggesting that two 


spendthrifts are happier than a spendthrift and a tightwad [even 


though] two spendthrifts are much more likely to end up in debt 


and have other financial problems," Small says. "It's not clear that 


what makes you happier is also going to make you more financially 


secure."


the current findings suggest that couples should talk about 


financial habits and practices early on in a relationship, and form a 


set of shared expectations, plans and goals. "I think doing that 


helps people recognize if the differences are too broad to 


overcome," she adds.


"Entrepreneurs create so much wealth in our society, but we don't 


understand what makes a person become an entrepreneur," says 


Wharton finance professor Nikolai Roussanov. "This question of 'why' 


is fascinating for economists because entrepreneurs benefit society 


as a whole to such a great degree. We would be worse off without 


them."


"Why do certain people take the entrepreneurial leap?"


His conclusion is that entrepreneurs have unique social aspirations 


that other people typically don't share. "They weigh risks and 


outcomes differently," he notes, which leads to atypical, but 


rational, conclusions about risks and opportunities. Contrary to 


common perception, entrepreneurs are not less averse to taking 


chances; they simply view relative hazards with a different eye.


Socially, Roussanov says, aspiring entrepreneurs do not want to 


merely keep up with the proverbial Jones; they want to get 


marginally ahead of them. "Absolute wealth is not as important to 


them as relative wealth." Entrepreneurs also save more and spend 


less as a portion of their incomes than other people, according to 


Roussanov. The consumptive value of money isn't their motivation. 


Rather it's the social esteem that comes with achieving 


incrementally greater wealth than they had previously, and than 


their perceived peer group has. Of course, "Who 'the Jones' are 


changes as you progress," Roussanov points out. "First you think, 'I 


know these guys are successful and I would like to be like them.' But 


as you progress, you change your comparisons. You want to be in 


the Forbes 400, then in the top 10 and so forth.


In his paper, Roussanov notes that "if the satisfaction brought by 


'getting ahead of the Joneses' outweighs the danger of falling 


behind, risky activities with highly idiosyncratic payoffs, such as 


entrepreneurship, can be particularly attractive." By contrast, 


"Other people may not have this preference for status. They look at 


the risks and say, 'This is too much for me.'"


What is perplexing about an entrepreneur's endeavors, Roussanov 


adds, is that, "from an economist's point of view, the risk in 


entrepreneurial ventures is high." These people "commit a large 


fraction of their human and financial capital to their ventures, thus 


exposing themselves to large undiversified risks," he writes in the 


paper. "Economic theory predicts that higher risk should be 


compensated by higher average return, [yet] returns on 


undiversified entrepreneurial investments are no higher than the 


average return on publicly traded equity."


For Luxury Goods Aficionados, Knowledge Equals Wealth


Many consumers buy high-end products to signal wealth and 


status to those around them, aided by explicit branding such as a 


large Mercedes symbol on the front of a car. But if consumers buy 


expensive goods in part to clearly communicate things like status 


to others, why would shoppers spend thousands of dollars on 


handbags or other goods that have no visible logos?


In the paper, "Subtle Signals of Inconspicuous Consumption," 


Wharton marketing professor Jonah Berger and Morgan Ward, a 


marketing professor at Southern Methodist University, suggest that 


manufacturers of consumer goods wanting to sell to a high-end, 


niche customer base should offer exclusive product lines with 


smaller logos and more subtle branding elements. Based on studies 


of consumer preference among ordinary shoppers and those who 


were more fashion conscious, the researchers found that "insiders" 


in a given consumption range (e.g., fashionistas, car enthusiasts, 


etc.) prefer products that identified them as being "in the know" 


only to a select group of peers.


The consumer study groups examined products with both highly 


visible branding, such as the word "Gucci" emblazoned in tall 


letters on a handbag, and more subtle signals of price -- for 


example, the signature cherry-red soles on Christian Louboutin 


shoes. 


The majority of "typical" consumers preferred the products with 


larger brand identifiers, and tended to misidentify products with 


subtler branding. Among products with subtle signals, "typical" 


consumers "thought the high-priced options were no more 


expensive than their cheap alternatives," the authors write. But 


the "insiders," in this case fashion students or people with an affinity 


for high fashion, not only could tell the difference between a low-


cost generic item and a high-priced item with a tiny logo, but also 


preferred the subtly-branded products.


To understand such "insider" shoppers, companies need to realize 


that the handbag these shoppers carry or shoes they wear is 


largely about sending signals, Berger notes, almost like 


communicating a coded message to members of a select group. 


"A Rolex is a widely recognized status symbol, but might be looked 


down upon by true watch enthusiasts," the paper states. "A 


Vacheron Constantin, on the other hand, will be invisible to most 


people, but respected by watch aficionados."


Another lesson, conversely, is that being selective with branding 


techniques comes with risk. A consumer goods company that 


wants to target high-end shoppers might select a subtle pattern or 


small logo, but that could turn off the majority of shoppers -- those 


who can't tell the difference between a cheaper product and the 


expensive item."Most people think a $6,000 Bottega Veneta bag is 


no more expensive that a cheap Wal-Mart bag that has no logo," 


Berger says.


According to Berger and Ward, from the point of view of an 


"insider," being identified as such is vitally important, to the point 


that they will opt for possibly being mistaken for lower-end shoppers 


by the masses in exchange for recognition by their fellow high-


fashion fans. The researchers also suggest that "discretely marked 


products, subtle but distinct styles or high-end brands that fly 


beneath the radar" have a longer life on the market than their less 


expensive, more loudly branded alternatives.


"The value of signals is that they distinguish social groups, so when 


outsiders start copying insiders' signals, insiders may abandon that 


product and search for a new signal," Berger says. "Because explicit 


signals, like large logos, are easier to observe, they are more likely to 


be poached or copied, and thus more likely to eventually be 


abandoned in favor of a new group marker."


That has clear implications for products with explicit brand 


markings, even on expensive high-end products. "Explicit status 


symbols may generate large sales in the short term, but this will only 


persist if enough of the buyers are truly wealthy," the researchers 


write. "If not, the symbolic value will shift towards being a marker of 


the wannabe rich, and sales will decline as consumers search for 


the next aspirational symbol."


More generally, the researchers suggest, the role of wealth as a 


status marker is changing, being replaced by knowledge or 


"cultural capital." With the expansion of credit and leasing 


programs, and the wider availability of knockoff items, "it is a lot 


easier now for someone who is not truly wealthy to be able to 


purchase something that seems expensive," Berger notes. "Cultural 


capital, though, remains elusive. Acquiring the right knowledge 


requires time, effort and the right connections -- things that are 


hard to fake."

Labels:


Comments: Post a Comment



<< Home

This page is powered by Blogger. Isn't yours?